« politiques publiques et instruments économiques et réglementaires pour la préservation de la biodiversité et des services écosystémiques »
Panel
- Julien Hardelin (Chef du bureau de la biodiversité et des ressources, Commissariat général au développement durable, La Défense)
- Harold Levrel (Professeur, AgroParisTech, CIRED, Nogent sur Marne)
- Julie Subervie (Directrice de recherche, INRAE, CEE-M, Montpellier)
- Laurence Tubiana (European Climate Foundation)
“What public policies and economic and regulatory instruments are needed to preserve biodiversity and ecosystem services?”
Round table at the FAERE annual conference
PEGE, Pôle européen de gestion et d’économie à Strasbourg
5 September 2024
We are all aware of the impact our societies are having on nature, following a pattern of development that is dooming the future if we do not find solutions quickly.
Yet nature, with its diversity of living forms and the links that bind them together, is a highly complex system.
Under these conditions, how can economists produce relevant recommendations and document choices, particularly transition choices, based on such diversity? In extremely varied contexts and on extremely varied scales.
Added to these difficulties are a number of strategies adopted by economic players to slow down political initiatives which, in the name of the fight against climate change and the collapse of biodiversity, would lead to fundamental changes in their markets.
The setbacks observed around the Green Pact for Europe are a case in point.
Laurence TUBIANA, an economist, academic and diplomat, has headed the European Climate Foundation since 2017. She notes that it is becoming increasingly difficult for economists who include climate issues in their work to make their voices heard at European level.
In particular, there is the issue of financing the transition.
Over the last five years, the prospect of the private sector increasing its level of contribution to the financing of the ecological transition, alongside public funds, has fuelled hope. Unfortunately, the objectives have not been achieved.
For Laurence TUBIANA, we now need to focus on tax issues. Taxation on flows. Taxation by sector of activity, such as the maritime sector, which pays little for its impacts.
Not forgetting tax incentives.
For Julien HARDELIN, Head of the Biodiversity and Resources Office at the French General Commission for Sustainable Development, at a more local level, planning tax could, for example, help to combat the artificialisation of land. It could no longer be seen solely as a source of revenue, but as a real tool for public policy. More broadly, economic instruments (taxation, payments for environmental services, etc.) have a key role to play in offering stakeholders incentives aligned with the preservation of biodiversity.
One of the challenges facing economists is that the hidden costs of environmental degradation and its impacts on the economy, which are often time-lagged, are still poorly understood and need to be better documented.
The valuations are multifactorial and complex.
Apart from the fact that economists have to broaden their traditional range of skills to include biodiversity issues, economics sometimes struggles to keep up with the complexity of the subject.
If we take the example of ecosystem services provided by nature, their evaluation in economic terms often remains imprecise.
For Harold LEVREL, professor at AgroParisTech, the models used in economics are not really adapted to biodiversity, because they are too simplistic. This makes it difficult to guide decisions on the management of ecosystems and natural resources, from maximum yields for fishing to the sustainable use of forests.
The complexity of the parameters to be taken into account destabilises the discipline.
Economics probably has more to say about the costs of maintaining biodiversity and the challenges of coordinating a wide range of players in a common territory to protect it.
It also has more to say about the ecological compensation mechanisms that could be implemented to restore an environment degraded by human activity, with a view to seeking equivalence ‘in kind’ in terms of biodiversity itself or the ecosystem services it provides.
Or about the right way to establish and produce ecological debt indicators (in biophysical and monetary units) to be entered on the liabilities side of production and operating accounts, for inclusion in extra-financial reports.
As far as payments for environmental services are concerned, the main aim should be to make the systems more efficient by seeking to reduce transaction costs and setting premiums that are sufficiently attractive to encourage changes in practices.
As far as public policies are concerned, the issue of environmentally harmful subsidies also needs to be better addressed.
The proportion of harmful subsidies varies greatly depending on whether the studies are carried out by Bercy or by research institutes.
Economics can easily put a figure on the losses associated with incentive measures that are rendered obsolete by subsidies with opposite effects. And so help to ensure that policies are more coherent.
For decision support, and there are many decisions to be made at all levels in the context of transition, the question arises as to whether it is preferable for environmental economists to concentrate on producing detailed assessments or to devote themselves to an economy of orders of magnitude.
For Julien HARDELIN, when it comes to biodiversity, economic evaluations in monetary form will always be imprecise, and will always need to be placed in a particular context. Let’s accept that.
But economic evaluations, used and interpreted appropriately, can provide orders of magnitude that are a valuable aid to decision-making, with the benefits of preserving biodiversity possibly exceeding the costs by several multiples. Valuations can also highlight the variety of ecosystem services and the multiple values associated with ecosystems.
Whether we are talking about nature-based solutions, the cost of restoring a wetland compared with the creation of civil engineering works and their maintenance, the benefits derived from public consultation, planning choices or economic development, local elected representatives and ministerial departments are often looking for economic arguments.
In these times of transition and adaptation, economic analysis services to support decision-makers are more necessary than ever. An economy of orders of magnitude is expected.
Harold Levrel believes that over the past 40 years, the evaluation of ecosystem services has done little to save natural areas. One indicator of this situation is the decline in spending on biodiversity by businesses in France since 2000, according to the CGDD’s environmental accounts, despite the fact that businesses are increasingly speaking out on the subject of their dependence on ecosystem services.
Julie SUBERVIE, Director of Research at INRAE, argues that recent work in the field of behavioural economics can contribute to the development of more relevant public policies.
The starting point is simple: the unexpected effects of non-rational choices cannot be covered by the usual economic theories.
When it comes to environmental issues, it is not uncommon to see economic players making choices that lead them to saw off the branch on which they are sitting. What are their decision-making mechanisms?
Behavioural economics is trying to find out.
At the same time, the social experiments it conducts with other economists make it possible to produce causal analyses of the effectiveness of certain measures, when economic theory is unable to predict what will happen.
In concrete terms, this method is essential when it comes to estimating the abatement cost of a tropical forest conservation project, in order to better calibrate ‘carbon credits’, for example.
On the issue of pesticides, too, recent research based on natural experiments has shown that there is a causal link between an increase in the doses of plant protection products used on farms and a rise in infant and child mortality.
Today, environmental economists are able to provide evidence that the doses are problematic in certain regions of the world (in the USA and Brazil in particular) because they worsen human health indicators.
However, as causal links become more clearly established, there are several signs that public policy is taking a step backwards.
Laurence TUBIANA wonders about this crossover.
Julie SUBERVIE points out that this accumulation of scientific evidence is in fact concomitant with a propensity on the part of public authorities to spend a lot of money supporting research that does not seem to be moving in the direction of a profound ecological transition. One example is the PARSADA programme (Strategic Action Plan for the Anticipation of the Potential European Withdrawal of Active Substances and the Development of Alternative Techniques for Crop Protection), the short-term objective of which is clearly stated and does not suggest any societal paradigm shift.
Behavioural economics has a bright future ahead of it.
Valéry DUBOIS
Thank you to Laurence TUBIANA, Julie SUBERVIE, Julien HARDELIN and Harold LEVREL